EACC

ECB | Natural rate estimates for the euro area: insights, uncertainties and shortcomings

Prepared by Claus Brand, Noëmie Lisack and Falk Mazelis
Estimates of the natural rate of interest, or r*, show trends that are of fundamental significance for monetary policy, but are subject to important caveats. r* is defined as the real rate of interest that is neither expansionary nor contractionary. Measures of r* are typically constructed as an equilibrium value towards which interest rates tend to gravitate in the medium to long term, as aggregate saving and investment imbalances abate and the inflationary or disinflationary pressures that may have developed as a consequence of those imbalances dissipate. These measures are also informative regarding the risk of short-term interest rates becoming constrained by their effective lower bound. However, available measures of r* are fraught with measurement and model specification challenges and are highly uncertain, reflecting, to different degrees, model, parameter, filter and real-time data uncertainty. While estimates of r* provide complementary information for monetary policy decisions and aid communication on the stance of monetary policy, these cannot be seen as a mechanical gauge of appropriate monetary policy at any point in time. In conducting monetary policy, there is no alternative to taking decisions on the basis of a comprehensive analysis of the data and their macroeconomic implications. In the euro area, in particular, the focus of such an assessment is threefold: the inflation outlook in light of the incoming economic and financial data, the dynamics of underlying inflation and the strength of monetary policy transmission.
Ranges of point estimates from different r* models indicate a very high degree of model uncertainty. Model uncertainty is the variability in estimates of r* that arises from using different models. Since r* is unobservable, economists rely on a range of models to estimate it. These models may incorporate different definitions of the benchmark rate, for example the instrument used by the central bank to conduct monetary policy. Different models may also rely on alternative determinants, such as measures of economic slack or the time horizons over which inflation eventually stabilises. Models can be clustered by type of measure – such as slow-moving equilibrium measures and cyclical inflation-stabilising measures. Slow-moving r* measures are anchored to long-run economic trends but may not capture short-term fluctuations. Cyclical r* measures reflect short-term dynamics and exhibit inflation-stabilising properties but can be sensitive to temporary shocks and are less stable. Balancing these trade-offs is challenging.

Chart A
Real natural rates of interest in the euro area

(percentages per annum)

Sources: ECB calculations, Eurosystem estimates, Federal Reserve Bank of New York and Consensus Economics.
Notes: Estimates displayed for survey-based, term structure-based and semi-structural measures are based on the same measures referred to in the box entitled “Estimates of the natural interest rate for the euro area: an update”, Economic Bulletin, Issue 1, ECB, 2024. The DSGE-based estimate is not included here. HLW-based measures, which do not ensure a stationary real rate gap, are displayed separately from other semi-structural measures. The latest observations are for the third quarter of 2024 for Holston, Laubach and Williams (2023), Grosse-Steffen, Lhuissier, Marx and Penalver (mimeo), and Carvalho (2023); and for the fourth quarter of 2024 for all other estimates.

Chart A shows a wide range of point estimates for the real natural rate. Following a modest post-pandemic increase, the updated range of point estimates of the real natural rate of interest for the euro area has remained broadly unchanged since the end of 2023 and is consistent with the estimates documented in Issue 1, 2024 of the Economic Bulletin.[1] We distinguish between four categories of measures. The median from survey-based measures is indicated by the red line. Measures shown by the dark blue area are derived from models of the term structure of interest rates. Those derived from semi-structural models are shown by the dark yellow area. Finally, three estimates derived from the Holston-Laubach-Williams (HLW) model are shown separately, by the light yellow area. The latter measures are not available for the fourth quarter of 2024.[2] Taking only the measures shown in the dark blue and dark yellow areas that were possible to update to the very end of 2024, the most recent estimates of real r* span a range between -½% and +½% (see the dark blue and dark yellow intervals corresponding to the fourth quarter of 2024 in Chart A).[3] The way to translate those measures into their nominal counterparts is measure-specific. Some of the models produce both real and nominal versions of r*, while others estimate only one version. In the latter case, the missing value must be derived by adding or subtracting the ECB’s 2% medium-term inflation target or the model-consistent medium-term inflation expectations from the model estimate. When the three estimates derived from versions of the HLW model are factored in, the range of real r* is -½% to 1% and the corresponding nominal range is 1¾% to 3%.[4] Referring only to those measures included in the dark blue and dark yellow areas for which an update to the end of 2024 is available, the estimates of the nominal r* from the most recent interval range between 1¾% and 2¼%. Given the estimation uncertainties highlighted in this box, such ranges should be viewed as merely indicative.
Natural rate estimates are further surrounded by uncertainties in model parameters. Point estimates typically display an outcome that is conditional on a single estimate of the model parameters – commonly the “most likely” value. However, the econometric methods used to estimate the model parameters generate a whole set of plausible alternative estimates. Bayesian estimation techniques, for example, concentrate on the probability distributions of parameters rather than on their fixed-point estimates. Embracing this approach allows the use of a distribution of values for each model’s r* estimate, which reflects the statistical uncertainty affecting the estimation of that model’s parameters. Taking one semi-structural model whose point estimate is included in the range shown in Chart A (the model by Brand and Mazelis, 2019), it can be seen that the parameter uncertainty surrounding each of the point estimates for r* can be quite large (Chart B, dark blue range).

Chart B
Parameter and filter uncertainty around the real natural rate estimates in the model by Brand and Mazelis

(percentages per annum)

Source: ECB calculations.
Notes: Estimates are based on Brand, C. and Mazelis, F., “Taylor-rule consistent estimates of the natural rate of interest”, Working Paper Series, No 2257, ECB, Frankfurt am Main, March 2019 (extended to include stochastic volatility in the output gap, a long-term interest rate, asset purchase effects and the effective lower bound). We employ the RISE toolbox for parameter estimation and regime-switching Kalman filtering, which enables the extraction of covariance matrices of unobserved states (see Maih, J. “Efficient perturbation methods for solving regime-switching DSGE models,” Working Paper, 01/2015, Norges Bank, 16 January 2015). Parameter and filter uncertainties are displayed as 95% uncertainty bands, calculated following the methods for statistical inference with the Kalman filter described in Chapter 13.7 of Hamilton, J.D., “Time Series Analysis”, Princeton University Press, 1994. Since computing the maximum likelihood estimate directly is impractical in our setting, we use the mode of the posterior distribution as an approximation. The filter uncertainty is based on the regime-specific covariance matrix of unobserved states from the predominant regime in the model, which features low volatility in the output gap and a policy rate that follows the Taylor rule. Considering regime-specific covariances or joint covariance matrices across different regimes would further enlarge the uncertainty ranges.

An additional source of uncertainty comes from the fact that r* is an unobservable variable that must be inferred from observable data – a challenge known as filtering. Since r* cannot be observed directly, we must deduce it from the economic data that we can measure. Accordingly, additional filter uncertainty is associated with obtaining an informative signal from the data. Like parameter uncertainty, the filter uncertainty range is time-varying. Cumulatively, parameter and filter uncertainty together can span up to several percentage points (Chart B, light blue range) even for a single model.[5]
Different data samples and revisions in backdata amplify the impact of filter uncertainty, leading to large ex post variations in in-sample point estimates of r* and adding yet another layer of uncertainty. Model-specific estimates of r* can vary significantly when observations are added or backdata are revised.[6] Chart C illustrates the considerable extent of this sensitivity using the widely referenced approach of Holston, Laubach and Williams (2023). Over time, as updates become available, revisions in previously obtained estimates can be as large as 1 percentage point. Most recently, end-of-sample point estimates have varied by similar magnitudes from one quarter to the next.

Chart C
Vintages of point estimates of the real natural rate of interest for the euro area from the model by Holston, Laubach and Williams

(percentages per annum)

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
Note: See Holston, K., Laubach, T. and Williams, J.C., “Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest after COVID-19”, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, No 1063, June 2023. The latest estimate, published for the third quarter of 2024, is also displayed at the lower end of the light yellow range in Chart A.

Despite the uncertainties involved, tracking broad movements in the natural rate over time provides qualitative insights into underlying economic trends. Notwithstanding the uncertainties associated with estimating r*, its trends contain information about developments in saving-investment imbalances that may create inflationary or disinflationary pressures, as well as about the extent to which the short-term interest rate might become constrained by the lower bound. The persistently low estimates of r* over the period 2015-22 displayed in Chart A, for example, reflect the persistent weakness in aggregate demand at the time and the low inflationary pressures that it generated. While in the post-pandemic environment estimates suggest some increase in r*, current estimates continue to be measurably below those prevailing before the global financial crisis, pointing to still lingering lower-bound risks in the event of sufficiently large disinflationary shocks.
The inherent uncertainties as well as conceptual shortcomings limit the usefulness of available natural rate estimates for conducting monetary policy in real time. Because of the multiple types of uncertainty and the focus on the short-term interest rate instrument – as opposed to broader measures of financing conditions, which can have a stronger impact on spending – the usefulness of r* as an indicator to support the calibration of the monetary policy stance is greatly limited, making it difficult to use as a rate-setting norm at policy meetings. Many models used do not construe r* as stabilising inflation in line with target but as merely indicating levels towards which interest rates gravitate over the longer term. As a function of historical shocks, such “equilibrium” interest rate measures are also largely backward-looking. By the time that equilibrium level is expected to be reached, the economy may well have already been exposed to further shocks, possibly causing the equilibrium rate of interest to drift and requiring monetary policy to offset these shocks. Furthermore, the connection between an r* defined in terms of the short-term interest rate instrument of monetary policy and the broader economy may itself change, as monetary policy transmission depends on a broader set of financing conditions – including the cost and availability of bank credit, and prices in a range of asset markets. The link between the short-term interest rate instrument and broader indicators for monetary policy is state-contingent and typically not stable. Accounting for these conceptual shortcomings and uncertainties is crucial for interpreting r* estimates.

The range reported in Chart A is also broadly consistent with the set of estimates published recently by the Bank for International Settlements. See Benigno, G., Hofmann, B., Nuño, G., Sandri, D, “Quo vadis, r*? The natural rate of interest after the pandemic”, BIS Quarterly Review, March 2024, pp. 17-30.
The HLW estimates are also shown separately, by the light yellow area, because of their methodological differences with respect to other semi-structural measures, shown by the dark yellow area. In particular, the family of HLW models (see Holston et al., 2017) posits a backward-looking relationship between the real interest rate gap, economic slack and inflation. Because of the inclusion of an accelerationist Phillips curve, the resulting r* estimate stabilises inflation around a random drift, i.e. an inflation level not necessarily close to the central bank’s inflation target. HLW-based approaches do not typically include an interest rate equation and thus have no mechanism to support a stationary real rate gap. Resulting estimates of persistently negative real rate gaps in the euro area are, however, challenging to reconcile with the inflation shortfalls observed over the period between the global financial crisis and the pandemic. Moreover, the marked flatness of the estimated Phillips and investment-savings curves amplifies filtering uncertainty, thus generating an “imprecision of the estimate” where, as acknowledged by Holston et al. (2017), “the average standard error for r* is very large, … and hence r* is barely identified”. On the theoretical foundations and econometrics of HLW, see Laubach, T. and Williams, J.C., “Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 85, No 4, November 2003, pp. 1063-1070, and Holston, K., Laubach, T. and Williams, J.C., “Measuring the natural rate of interest: International trends and determinants”, Journal of International Economics, Elsevier, Vol. 108, Supplement 1, May 2017, pages S59-S75.
Values reported in this box for both real and nominal r* are rounded to the nearest 25 basis point increment.
As a cross-reference, the HLW estimate for the euro area in the third quarter of 2024 published by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York was at 1.84% in nominal terms. For other HLW-type specifications tracked by the Eurosystem, see the approach explained by Carvalho, A., “The euro area natural interest rate – Estimation and importance for monetary policy”, Banco de Portugal Economic Studies, Vol. IX, No. 3, July 2023.
The wide dispersion is due in part to the relatively flat aggregate demand and Phillips curves embedded in semi-structural models used for estimating r* and is not specific to the Brand and Mazelis model. In comparison, the HLW estimates from the third quarter of 2024 mentioned earlier display an additional observability challenge, leading to a cumulative parameter and filter uncertainty range that is greater by an order of magnitude. Given uncertainty bands as large as +/- 10 percentage points, it is not clear whether the HLW estimate is ever different from 0% or any other interest rate level observed throughout the sample period. Fiorentini et al. (2018) demonstrate that flat aggregate demand and Phillips curves significantly increase filter uncertainty. See Fiorentini, G., Galesi, A., Pérez-Quirós, G. and Sentana, E., “The rise and fall of the natural interest rate”, Working Papers, No 1822, Banco de España, 2018.
All unobserved variable estimates suffer from the issue of data revisions and differences in data vintages. As highlighted by Orphanides and van Norden (2002), real-time estimates of the output gap are particularly unreliable as a result of substantial data revisions. See Orphanides, A. and van Norden, S., “The Unreliability of Output-Gap Estimates in Real Time”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 84, No 4, November 2002, pp. 569-583.

 
Compliments of the European Central BankThe post ECB | Natural rate estimates for the euro area: insights, uncertainties and shortcomings first appeared on European American Chamber of Commerce New York [EACCNY] | Your Partner for Transatlantic Business Resources.

EACC

OECD | Development finance needs major overhaul to achieve global goals

The gap between development financing needs and available resources could swell to USD 6.4 trillion by 2030 without a major overhaul of the financing system, according to a new OECD report.
The Global Outlook on Financing Sustainable Development 2025: Towards a more resilient and inclusive architecture shows that although total external finance to developing countries reached USD 5.24 trillion in 2022, it remained significantly below the USD 9.24 trillion estimated to be required annually to achieve the 2030 Agenda.
Financing needs have risen by 36% between 2015 and 2022, due in large part to climate change and geopolitical uncertainty, but resources provided have only increased by 22% over the same period – a 60% gap. Without an agreement this year on major reform of the international financing architecture, the report estimates that the financing gap will balloon to USD 6.4 trillion by 2030.

“The development financing gap is not insurmountable. The challenge lies in mobilising resources at scale, channelling financial assets into transformative investments such as clean energy transitions and sustainable infrastructure,” OECD Secretary-General Mathias Cormann said.
The report, published ahead of the upcoming Conference on Financing for Development in Seville, calls for updating the financing framework for post-2025 to redirect the capital available globally, starting with balancing ambition and practicality in addressing sustainable development priorities. Inclusive governance and policy coherence are critical to overcoming the hurdles, as disparities in decision-making structures and resource allocation undermine global trust and co-operation.
Despite a rebound from the COVID-19 pandemic, financing for sustainable development is still insufficient to meet growing needs, the report shows. While official development assistance (ODA) hit a record of USD 223.3 billion in 2023 among members of the OECD Development Assistance Committee (DAC), further commitments are required to ensure effective support to fill the needs of partner countries, particularly for investments in clean energy transition.
Remittances have been the dominant source of external financial flows to developing countries, a more than 30% increase since 2015 to reach USD 476 billion in 2023. However, transfer fees remain twice the level of the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) target of 3%, resulting in USD 16 billion in annual losses to households sending and receiving the money.
Strengthening domestic resource mobilisation is key for effective state functioning, but the tax-to-GDP ratio in low-income countries remains an average 11.44% in 2022, below the recommended 15% threshold. Meanwhile, debt levels in developing countries continue to rise. Between 2015 and 2024, the number of countries in debt difficulty and at high risk of debt distress increased from 16 to 24 and from three to 11, respectively.
As the economic gap between rich and poor nations has diverged rather than converged, the report calls for actions to renew the development financing system to better align money for sustainable development. For instance, there are already USD 461 trillion worldwide in financial assets — sufficient to cover the gap 115 times over — but the misalignment of these resources, including the USD 1.53 trillion spent on subsidising fossil fuels in 2022, needs to be redirected to achieve the 2030 Agenda.
To enhance accountability and transparency in resource allocation, the report also urges strengthening the global financing for development monitoring system to restore trust among all countries.
The Global Outlook provides a basis for the upcoming discussions at the Fourth International Conference on Financing for Development in Seville, where from 30 June countries will negotiate how to reform the global financing architecture for the implementation of the SDGs.
Download the report.

 
Compliments of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and DevelopmentThe post OECD | Development finance needs major overhaul to achieve global goals first appeared on European American Chamber of Commerce New York [EACCNY] | Your Partner for Transatlantic Business Resources.

EACC

The Fed | Federal Reserve Board releases the hypothetical scenarios for its annual stress test

The Federal Reserve Board on Wednesday released the hypothetical scenarios for its annual stress test, which helps ensure that large banks can lend to households and businesses even in a severe recession. Additionally, the Board released two hypothetical elements designed to probe different risks through its “exploratory analysis” of the banking system. The exploratory analysis will not affect bank capital requirements.
The Board’s annual stress test evaluates the resilience of large banks by estimating losses, net revenue, and capital levels—which provide a cushion against losses—under hypothetical recession scenarios that extend two years into the future. This year, 22 banks will be tested against a severe global recession with heightened stress in both commercial and residential real estate markets, as well as in corporate debt markets. The scenarios are not forecasts and should not be interpreted as predictions of future economic conditions.
In the 2025 stress test scenario, the U.S. unemployment rate rises nearly 5.9 percentage points, to a peak of 10 percent. The unemployment rate increase is accompanied by severe market volatility, a widening of corporate bond spreads, and a collapse in asset prices, including about a 33 percent decline in house prices and a 30 percent decline in commercial real estate prices.
Large banks with substantial trading or custodial operations are also required to incorporate a counterparty default scenario component to estimate potential losses from the unexpected default of the firm’s largest counterparty amid an acute market shock. In addition, banks with large trading operations will be tested against a global market shock component that primarily stresses their trading and related positions.
The table below shows the components of the annual stress test that apply to each bank, based on data as of the third quarter of 2024.
This year’s exploratory analysis includes two separate hypothetical elements that will assess the resilience of the banking system to a wider range of risks. One of the hypothetical elements examines how banks would react to credit and liquidity shocks in the non-bank financial institution sector during a severe global recession.
The second element of the exploratory analysis includes a market shock that will be applied only to the largest and most complex banks. This shock hypothesizes the failure of five large hedge funds with reduced global economic activity and higher inflation.
The exploratory analysis is distinct from the stress test and will explore additional hypothetical risks to the broader banking system, rather than focusing on firm-specific results. The Board will publish aggregate results for the exploratory analysis alongside the annual stress test results in June 2025.
As the Board previously announced, it plans to take steps soon to reduce the volatility of stress test results and begin to improve model transparency in the 2025 stress test. Additionally, it intends to begin the public comment process on its comprehensive changes to the stress test this year.

Make Full Screen

Bank1

Subject to global market shock
Subject to counterparty default

American Express Company

Bank of America Corporation
X
X

The Bank of New York Mellon Corporation

X

Barclays US LLC
X
X

BMO Financial Corp.

Capital One Financial Corporation

The Charles Schwab Corporation

Citigroup Inc.
X
X

DB USA Corporation
X
X

The Goldman Sachs Group, Inc.
X
X

JPMorgan Chase & Co.
X
X

M&T Bank Corporation2

Morgan Stanley
X
X

Northern Trust Corporation

The PNC Financial Services Group, Inc.

RBC US Group Holdings LLC2

State Street Corporation

X

TD Group US Holdings LLC

Truist Financial Corporation

UBS Americas Holding LLC

U.S. Bancorp

Wells Fargo & Company
X
X

1. The information listed in this table is based on third quarter 2024 data. Return to text
2. M&T Bank Corporation and RBC US Group Holdings LLC elected to opt into the 2025 stress test. Return to text

For media inquiries, please email media@frb.gov or call 202-452-2955.
 
Compliments of the United States Federal Reserve BoardThe post The Fed | Federal Reserve Board releases the hypothetical scenarios for its annual stress test first appeared on European American Chamber of Commerce New York [EACCNY] | Your Partner for Transatlantic Business Resources.

EACC

ECB | What happens when US and euro area monetary policy decouple?

Blog post by By Stefan Gebauer, Georgios Georgiadis, Fédéric Holm-Hadulla and Thomas Kostka | The monetary policies of the ECB and the US Federal Reserve are not always in sync. But how does the Fed’s policy affect the euro area economy? This ECB Blog looks at how monetary policy in the United States travels across the Atlantic and what this means for the ECB.
The global economy is interconnected. Central banks’ monetary policies therefore often affect other economies. These “monetary policy spillovers” are particularly relevant for economies as closely linked as the United States and the euro area. Spillovers from US monetary policy initially work in the opposite direction to ECB monetary policy, but then later in the same direction. For instance, a surprise tightening of US policy leads to an initial increase in euro area inflation as the euro weakens. However, over time, tighter US monetary policy drags down euro area inflation much like tighter ECB policy would.
In more detail, when the Fed unexpectedly raises interest rates to curb inflation and economic activity, euro area inflation increases on average over the three months following the announcement. This is because, following a surprise tightening in the United States, the euro immediately weakens against the dollar. And that makes imported goods more expensive. This effect is particularly relevant for euro area imports priced in US dollars, such as oil and other commodities. The weaker euro also cheapens euro area exports to the United States. This, in turn, supports economic activity and prices in the euro area slightly. Hence, over the short run, the spillovers from a surprise US monetary policy tightening on the euro area economy work in the opposite direction to the effects of a monetary policy tightening by the ECB. This is visible in the left-hand parts of each subplot of Chart 1.
Over time, however, the initial inflationary impact of higher policy rates in the US is compensated by broader disinflationary pressures. Tighter US financing conditions spill over to the euro area through global financial markets, leading to a slowdown in euro area economic activity. At the same time, the Fed’s tightening also weighs on economic activity in the US over time, with lower demand by US households and firms also implying lower imports from the euro area. Overall, the medium-term effects of US monetary policy on the euro area therefore resemble the dampening impact of similar actions by the ECB. This means that – while the immediate impacts might differ – in the medium term US monetary policy pushes the euro area economy in the same direction as euro area policy changes would. These effects can be seen for the same variables on the right-hand parts of each subplot in Chart 1.

Chart 1
Impact of euro area (EA) and US monetary policy shocks on the euro area economy

Source: ECB staff calculations.
Notes: Impulse responses (IR) for selected horizons, scaled to 25 bps reaction in the 3-months OIS rate and the 3-months US Treasury bill rate, respectively, derived by local projections (Jorda (2005)). ECB and Fed monetary policy shocks are identified via high-frequency movements in short-term market rates over a narrow window (ca. 135 minutes) around ECB and Fed policy meetings applying “poor man’s” sign restrictions as in Jarocinski and Karadi (2020). Euro area shocks are extracted from the policy-event database of Altavilla et al. (2019). The euro area outcome variables are: (i) the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices (left panel), (ii) industrial production (right panel). All variables are in log-levels. The local projections control for the lagged dependent variables, the Euro-Dollar exchange rate, euro area exports to and euro area imports from the US, the euro area unemployment rate, log-levels of US industrial production and the US Consumer Price Index, the euro area Composite Indicator of Systemic Stress (CISS), the IMF Commodities Price Index, the GDP-weighted 10-year yields on euro area sovereign bonds, the euro area 3-months OIS rate, and the other jurisdiction’s monetary policy shocks. Moreover, forward dummies for the COVID-19 pandemic (from March 2020 to April 2023) and the war in Ukraine (from March 2022 onwards) enter the model at the same horizon as the dependent variables. All data are at monthly frequency for the 2002m1-2024m5 period. Standard errors are derived from the Newey and West (1987) estimator to account for autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity. Results are comparable to estimates presented in Ca’ Zorzi et al. (2023). Additional details are available in Gebauer et al. (2025).

How did we come up with these findings?
We used an empirical method called local projections to analyse the impact of US monetary policy surprises, or “shocks”, on the euro area. Shocks correspond to the change in monetary policy that goes beyond the regular response of a central bank to economic developments. Studying such shocks provides clearer insights into the cause-and-effect relationships of policy with subsequent economic developments. The monetary policy shocks are derived by measuring financial market movements in a tight time window around monetary policy decisions on either side of the Atlantic. Having isolated the shocks, we integrated them into a local projections model that – based on historical regularities – tells us how economic variables, such as euro area inflation and industrial production, respond to US and euro area monetary policy shocks over time. This approach helps distinguish between short-term and medium-term effects and thus provides a nuanced understanding of how policy impacts unfold.
And why is it important?
Our findings have important implications for the conduct of the ECB’s monetary policy in the presence US monetary policy spillovers. Simply mimicking a surprise move in US policy rates might avert short-term spillovers, such as higher (or lower) inflation. Over the medium term, however, this would add to the tightening (or easing) impulse from abroad which, all else equal, would create risks that the ECB in turn undershoots (or overshoots) its domestic inflation target. Accounting for such medium-term spillovers is important because of the explicit medium-term orientation embedded in the ECB’s inflation target.
The views expressed in each blog entry are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of the European Central Bank and the Eurosystem.
Check out The ECB Blog and subscribe for future posts.
For topics relating to banking supervision, why not have a look at The Supervision Blog?
References
Altavilla, C., Brugnolini, L., Gürkaynak, R. S., Motto, R., and Ragusa, G. (2019). Measuring euro area monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 108:162–179.
Ca’ Zorzi, M., Dedola, L., Georgiadis, G., Jarocinski, M., Stracca, L., and Strasser, G. (2023). Making waves: Monetary policy and its asymmetric spillovers in a
globalised world. International Journal of Central Banking, 19(2):95–144.
Gebauer, S., Georgiadis, G., Holm-Hadulla, F., and Kostka, T. (2025). Macroeconomic effects of (de-) synchronized monetary policy shocks. mimeo.
Georgiadis, G. and Jarocinski, M. (2023). Global spillovers from multi-dimensional us monetary policy. ECB Working Paper Series, 2881.
Jarocinski, M. and Karadi, P. (2020). Deconstructing monetary policy surprises—the role of information shocks. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 12(2):1–43.
Jorda, O. (2005). Estimation and inference of impulse responses by local projections. American Economic Review, 95(1):161–182.
Newey, W. K. and West, K. D. (1987). A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica, 55:703– 708.
 
Compliments of the European Central BankThe post ECB | What happens when US and euro area monetary policy decouple? first appeared on European American Chamber of Commerce New York [EACCNY] | Your Partner for Transatlantic Business Resources.

EACC

ECB | Europe has strengths it can build on

Blog post by Christine Lagarde, President of the European Central Bank, and Ursula von der Leyen, President of the European Commission | Remaining competitive is fundamental for Europe’s future. We need faster economic growth and higher productivity to protect the quality of life for Europeans – from their jobs and incomes to their security and welfare.
Europe must act. Our competitiveness is at risk. While a global revolution in artificial intelligence unfolds, the EU could find itself on the sidelines. Our traditional manufacturing champions are losing global market share. Geopolitical shifts are turning dependencies into vulnerabilities and burdening our companies with high energy prices.
Europe must and will find its place in this new world. The prospects for our continent are better than they might seem. The EU has strengths on which it can build – and it has a plan to fix its weaknesses.
Europe has strong economic fundamentals. We have institutions governed by the rule of law, and an independent central bank committed to price stability. Inflation is returning to the ECB’s 2% target, allowing borrowing costs to fall. Public debts and deficits are lower than in other major economies.
Europe also has the necessary ingredients to catch up in the technological race. The EU turns out almost as many STEM graduates per million inhabitants as the United States. That talent produces a lot of ideas: Europe’s share in global patent grants is close to that of the United States. And we have the money to finance them, with households saving around €1.3 trillion every year.
We have an opportunity to bring down energy prices in a lasting way. The shift to secure, low-cost clean energy sources is on track: by 2030, over 40% of our energy consumption will come from renewables. And we are well placed to become a global hub for clean tech innovation, especially as some countries strike out in a different direction.
While others must cut their dependencies by building up domestic capacity, the EU can choose from a broader set of options owing to its unique position in global trade. We are the top trading partner for over 70 nations and we continue to strike new agreements, most recently with 400 million Latin Americans. And in a deal with the EU, what you see is what you get.
But these strengths are meaningless if Europe is hamstrung by its weaknesses. We need profound change on three fronts.
First, we need to make the EU an easier place for innovative companies to grow. Only one-third of university patents in Europe are commercialised, while companies that try to scale up in our Single Market face many internal barriers. Despite our savings, entrepreneurs lack access to risk capital, because capital markets are still too fragmented.
Second, we need to make Europe a better place to invest. Two out of three EU companies say that regulation is a key obstacle to investment, while just 14% of them are using AI. Firms still face long permitting procedures, onerous reporting requirements and diverging enforcement of digital rules.
Third, we need to make doing business in Europe cheaper, especially in terms of energy costs. While the shift to renewables creates good jobs and strengthens energy security and independence, it also comes with greater intermittency and greater energy losses through curtailment. For the benefits of decarbonisation to show up in companies’ bills, we need massive investment in grids and storage and smarter market design.
Europe has got the message. This week, the European Commission presented its Competitiveness Compass which sets out ambitious proposals to address these shortcomings. From now on, the EU will strive not only to lower the barriers facing companies, but also to ensure that they have the resources they need to thrive here – be it finance, compute, energy or skills.
For example, the Commission will propose a so-called “28th regime” for innovative companies, allowing them to benefit from a single legal framework across the EU for aspects of corporate law, insolvency, labour law and taxation. It will launch a plan for a Savings and Investments Union, which will ensure that innovative companies can find the financial backing they need.
The EU will also give companies access to our world-leading network of supercomputers. This will help develop new advanced technologies and spread AI faster among established champions. The ECB will play its part too by keeping Europe at the forefront of digital payment technologies, including through the digital euro project.
In parallel, the regulatory burden will be lightened by an unprecedented simplification effort, starting next month. This will include a far-reaching simplification of legislation on sustainable finance reporting and due diligence. And energy prices will be brought down through a range of measures to integrate markets, increase contracted energy and reduce taxes.
This is only a snapshot of what lies ahead. Companies and households want to see action – and a wave of actions are coming. We can no longer squander our strengths with self-imposed handicaps. There is too much at stake. We are ready to do whatever is necessary to bring Europe back on track.
Check out The ECB Blog and subscribe for future posts.
 
Compliments of the European Central BankThe post ECB | Europe has strengths it can build on first appeared on European American Chamber of Commerce New York [EACCNY] | Your Partner for Transatlantic Business Resources.

EACC

European Commission | First rules of the Artificial Intelligence Act are now applicable

As of Sunday, 2 February, the first rules under the Artificial Intelligence Act (AI Act) started to apply. This includes the AI system definition, AI literacy, as well as a very limited number of prohibited AI use cases outlined in the AI Act that pose unacceptable risks in the EU.
To facilitate innovation in AI, the Commission will publish guidelines on AI system definition. This aims to assist the industry in determining whether a software system constitutes an AI system.
The Commission will also release a living repository of AI literacy practices gathered from AI systems’ providers and deployers. This will encourage learning and exchange among them while ensuring that users develop the necessary skills and understanding to effectively use AI technologies.
To help ensure compliance with the AI Act, the Commission will publish guidelines on the prohibited AI practices that are posing unacceptable risks to citizens’ safety and fundamental rights.
These guidelines will explain the legal concepts and provide practical use cases, based on stakeholder input. They are not binding and will be updated as necessary. The Commission has launched several initiatives to promote innovation in AI, from the AI innovation package supporting startups and SMEs to the upcoming AI Factories which will provide access to the massive computing power that start-ups, industry and researchers need to develop their AI models and systems.
More information and the guidelines will be available here.
(For more information: Thomas Regnier — Tel.: + 32 2 299 10 99; Nika Blazevic — Tel. + 32 2 299 27 17) 
 
Compliments of the European CommissionThe post European Commission | First rules of the Artificial Intelligence Act are now applicable first appeared on European American Chamber of Commerce New York [EACCNY] | Your Partner for Transatlantic Business Resources.

EACC

European Commission | An EU Compass to regain competitiveness and secure sustainable prosperity

Today, the Commission presents the Competitiveness Compass, the first major initiative of this mandate providing a strategic and clear framework to steer the Commission’s work.
The Compass sets a path for Europe to become the place where future technologies, services, and clean products are invented, manufactured, and put on the market, while being the first continent to become climate neutral.
Over the last two decades, Europe has not kept pace with other major economies due to a persistent gap in productivity growth. The EU has what is needed to reverse this trend with its talented and educated workforce, capital, savings, Single Market, unique social infrastructure, provided it acts urgently to tackle longstanding barriers and structural weaknesses that hold it back.
President of the European Commission, Ursula von der Leyen, said: “Europe has everything it needs to succeed in the race to the top. But, at the same time, we must fix our weaknesses to regain competitiveness. The Competitiveness Compass transforms the excellent recommendations of the Draghi report into a roadmap. So now we have a plan. We have the political will. What matters is speed and unity. The world is not waiting for us. All Member States agree on this. So, let’s turn this consensus into action.”
Three core areas for action: innovation, decarbonisation and security
The Draghi Report identified three transformational imperatives to boost competitiveness, and the Compass sets out an approach and a selection of flagship measures to translate each of these imperatives into reality:

Closing the innovation gap: The EU must reignite its innovation engine. We want to create a habitat for young innovative start-ups, promote industrial leadership in high growth sectors based on deep technologies and promote the diffusion of technologies across established companies and SMEs. In this respect, the Commission will propose ‘AI Gigafactories’ and ‘Apply AI‘ initiatives to drive development and industrial adoption of AI in key sectors. It will table action plans for advanced materials, quantum, biotech, robotics and space technologies. A dedicated EU Start-up and Scale-up Strategy will address the obstacles that are preventing new companies from emerging and scaling up. A proposal for a 28th legal regime will simplify applicable rules, including relevant aspects of corporate law, insolvency, labour and tax law, and reduce the costs of failure. This will make it possible for innovative companies to benefit from one single set of rules wherever they invest and operate in the Single Market.

A joint roadmap for decarbonisation and competitiveness: The Compass identifies high and volatile energy prices as a key challenge and sets out areas for intervention to facilitate access to clean, affordable energy. The upcoming Clean Industrial Deal will set out a competitiveness-driven approach to decarbonisation, aimed at securing the EU as an attractive location for manufacturing, including for energy intensive industries, and promoting clean tech and new circular business models. An Affordable Energy Action Plan will help bring down energy prices and costs, while an Industrial Decarbonisation Accelerator Act will extend accelerated permitting to sectors in transition. In addition, the Compass foresees tailor-made action plans for energy intensive sectors, such as steel, metals, and chemicals, sectors which are the backbone of the European manufacturing system, but are the most vulnerable in this phase of the transition.

Reducing excessive dependencies and increasing security. The EU’s ability to diversify and reduce dependencies will hinge on effective partnerships. The EU already has the largest and fastest growing network of trade agreements in the world covering 76 countries that account for almost half of the EU’s trade. To keep diversifying and strengthening our supply chains, the Compass refers to a new range of Clean Trade and Investment Partnerships to help secure supply of raw materials, clean energy, sustainable transport fuels, and clean tech from across the world. Within the internal market, the review of the Public Procurement rules will allow for the introduction of a European preference in public procurement for critical sectors and technologies.

Five horizontal enablers for competitiveness
The three pillars are complemented by five horizontal enablers, which are essential to underpin competitiveness across all sectors:

Simplification: This enabler aims at reducing drastically the regulatory and administrative burden. It also involves a systematic effort to make procedures for accessing EU funds and getting EU administrative decisions simpler, faster, and lighter. The upcoming Omnibus proposal will simplify sustainability reporting, due diligence, and taxonomy. Furthermore, the Commission will facilitate doing business for thousands of small mid-cap companies. The Compass sets a target of cutting by at least 25% the administrative burden for firms and by at least 35% for SMEs.

Lowering barriers to the Single Market: For 30 years, the Single Market has been Europe’s tried and tested engine for competitiveness. To improve its functioning across all industries, a Horizontal Single Market Strategy will modernise the governance framework, removing intra-EU barriers and preventing the creation of new ones. In addition, the Commission will take the opportunity to make standard-setting processes faster and more accessible, in particular for SMEs and start-ups.

Financing competitiveness. The EU lacks an efficient capital market that turns savings into investments. The Commission will present a European Savings and Investments Union to create new savings and investment products, provide incentives for risk capital, and ensure investments flow seamlessly across the EU. A refocused EU budget will streamline access to EU funds in line with EU priorities.

Promoting skills and quality jobs. The foundation of Europe’s competitiveness is its people. To ensure a good match between skills and labour market demands, the Commission will present an initiative to build a Union of Skills focusing on investment, adult and lifelong learning, future-proof skills creation, skill retention, fair mobility, attracting and integrating qualified talent from abroad and the recognition of different types of training to enable people to work across our Union.

Better coordination of policies at EU and national level. The Commission will introduce a Competitiveness Coordination Tool, which will work with Member States to ensure implementation at EU and national level of shared EU policy objectives, identify cross-border projects of European interest, and pursue related reforms and investments. In the next Multiannual Financial Framework, a Competitiveness Fund will replace multiple existing EU financial instruments with similar objectives, providing financial support to the implementation of actions under the Competitiveness Coordination Tool.

Background
On 27 November 2024, President von der Leyen announced a Competitiveness Compass as the first major initiative of the Commission in this mandate, building on the Draghi report and providing the framework for the Commission’s work on competitiveness in this mandate.
In her State of the European Union Speech of 2023, President von der Leyen announced to have asked former Italian Prime Minister Mario Draghi to prepare a report on the future of European Competitiveness. The Report warns that Europe will no longer be able to rely on many of the factors that have supported growth in the past. It lays out a clear diagnosis and provides concrete recommendations to put Europe onto a different trajectory.  Many of the recommendations are already reflected in the Political Guidelines and mission letters by the President to the members of the College.
 
Compliments of the European CommissionThe post European Commission | An EU Compass to regain competitiveness and secure sustainable prosperity first appeared on European American Chamber of Commerce New York [EACCNY] | Your Partner for Transatlantic Business Resources.

EACC

ECB | Monetary Policy Statement: Christine Lagarde, President of the ECB, Luis de Guindos, Vice-President of the ECB

Good afternoon, the Vice-President and I welcome you to our press conference.
The Governing Council today decided to lower the three key ECB interest rates by 25 basis points. In particular, the decision to lower the deposit facility rate – the rate through which we steer the monetary policy stance – is based on our updated assessment of the inflation outlook, the dynamics of underlying inflation and the strength of monetary policy transmission.
The disinflation process is well on track. Inflation has continued to develop broadly in line with the staff projections and is set to return to our two per cent medium-term target in the course of this year. Most measures of underlying inflation suggest that inflation will settle at around our target on a sustained basis. Domestic inflation remains high, mostly because wages and prices in certain sectors are still adjusting to the past inflation surge with a substantial delay. But wage growth is moderating as expected, and profits are partially buffering the impact on inflation.
Our recent interest rate cuts are gradually making new borrowing less expensive for firms and households. At the same time, financing conditions continue to be tight, also because our monetary policy remains restrictive and past interest rate hikes are still transmitting to the stock of credit, with some maturing loans being rolled over at higher rates. The economy is still facing headwinds but rising real incomes and the gradually fading effects of restrictive monetary policy should support a pick-up in demand over time.
We are determined to ensure that inflation stabilises sustainably at our two per cent medium-term target. We will follow a data-dependent and meeting-by-meeting approach to determining the appropriate monetary policy stance. In particular, our interest rate decisions will be based on our assessment of the inflation outlook in light of the incoming economic and financial data, the dynamics of underlying inflation and the strength of monetary policy transmission. We are not pre-committing to a particular rate path.
The decisions taken today are set out in a press release available on our website.
I will now outline in more detail how we see the economy and inflation developing and will then explain our assessment of financial and monetary conditions.
Economic activity
The economy stagnated in the fourth quarter, according to Eurostat’s preliminary flash estimate. It is set to remain weak in the near term. Surveys indicate that manufacturing continues to contract while services activity is expanding. Consumer confidence is fragile, and households have not yet drawn sufficient encouragement from rising real incomes to significantly increase their spending.
Nevertheless, the conditions for a recovery remain in place. While the labour market has softened over recent months it continues to be robust, with the unemployment rate staying low, at 6.3 per cent in December. A solid job market and higher incomes should strengthen consumer confidence and allow spending to rise. More affordable credit should also boost consumption and investment over time. Provided trade tensions do not escalate, exports should support the recovery as global demand rises.
Fiscal and structural policies should make the economy more productive, competitive and resilient. We welcome the European Commission’s Competitiveness Compass, which provides a concrete roadmap for action. It is crucial to follow up, with further concrete and ambitious structural policies, on Mario Draghi’s proposals for enhancing European competitiveness and on Enrico Letta’s proposals for empowering the Single Market. Governments should implement their commitments under the EU’s economic governance framework fully and without delay. This will help bring down budget deficits and debt ratios on a sustained basis, while prioritising growth-enhancing reforms and investment.
Inflation
Annual inflation increased to 2.4 per cent in December, up from 2.2 per cent in November. As in the previous two months, the increase was expected and primarily reflected past sharp drops in energy prices falling out of the calculation. Along with a month-on-month increase in December, this led energy prices slightly higher on an annual basis, after four consecutive declines. Food price inflation edged down to 2.6 per cent and goods inflation to 0.5 per cent. Services inflation edged up to 4.0 per cent.
Most underlying inflation indicators have been developing in line with a sustained return of inflation to our medium-term target. Domestic inflation, which closely tracks services inflation, has remained high, as wages and some services prices are still adjusting to the past inflation surge with a substantial delay. At the same time, recent signals point to continued moderation in wage pressures and to the buffering role of profits.
We expect inflation to fluctuate around its current level in the near term. It should then settle sustainably at around the two per cent medium-term target. Easing labour cost pressures and the continuing impact of our past monetary policy tightening on consumer prices should help this process. While market-based indicators of inflation compensation have largely reversed the declines observed in the autumn, most measures of longer-term inflation expectations continue to stand at around 2 per cent.
Risk assessment
The risks to economic growth remain tilted to the downside. Greater friction in global trade could weigh on euro area growth by dampening exports and weakening the global economy. Lower confidence could prevent consumption and investment from recovering as fast as expected. This could be amplified by geopolitical risks, such as Russia’s unjustified war against Ukraine and the tragic conflict in the Middle East, which could disrupt energy supplies and further weigh on global trade. Growth could also be lower if the lagged effects of monetary policy tightening last longer than expected. It could be higher if easier financing conditions and falling inflation allow domestic consumption and investment to rebound faster.
Inflation could turn out higher if wages or profits increase by more than expected. Upside risks to inflation also stem from the heightened geopolitical tensions, which could push energy prices and freight costs higher in the near term and disrupt global trade. Moreover, extreme weather events, and the unfolding climate crisis more broadly, could drive up food prices by more than expected. By contrast, inflation may surprise on the downside if low confidence and concerns about geopolitical events prevent consumption and investment from recovering as fast as expected, if monetary policy dampens demand by more than expected, or if the economic environment in the rest of the world worsens unexpectedly. Greater friction in global trade would make the euro area inflation outlook more uncertain.
Financial and monetary conditions
Market interest rates in the euro area have risen since our December meeting, partly mirroring higher rates in global financial markets. While financing conditions remain tight, our interest rate cuts are gradually making it less expensive for firms and households to borrow.
The average interest rate on new loans to firms declined to 4.5 per cent in November, while the cost of issuing market-based debt remained at 3.6 per cent. The average rate on new mortgages edged down to 3.5 per cent.
Growth in bank lending to firms rose to 1.5 per cent in December, up from 1.0 per cent in November, amid a strong monthly flow. Growth in debt securities issued by firms moderated to 3.2 per cent in annual terms. Mortgage lending continued to rise gradually but remained muted overall, with an annual growth rate of 1.1 per cent.
Credit standards for business loans tightened again in the fourth quarter of 2024, having broadly stabilised over the previous four quarters, as reported in our latest bank lending survey. The renewed tightening mainly reflected banks becoming more concerned about the risks faced by their customers and less willing to take on risks themselves. Demand for loans by firms increased slightly in the fourth quarter but remained weak overall. Credit standards for mortgages were broadly unchanged, after three quarters of easing, while the demand for mortgages again increased strongly, mainly because of more attractive interest rates.
Conclusion
The Governing Council today decided to lower the three key ECB interest rates by 25 basis points. In particular, the decision to lower the deposit facility rate – the rate through which we steer the monetary policy stance – is based on our updated assessment of the inflation outlook, the dynamics of underlying inflation and the strength of monetary policy transmission. We are determined to ensure that inflation stabilises sustainably at our two per cent medium-term target. We will follow a data-dependent and meeting-by-meeting approach to determining the appropriate monetary policy stance. In particular, our interest rate decisions will be based on our assessment of the inflation outlook in light of the incoming economic and financial data, the dynamics of underlying inflation and the strength of monetary policy transmission. We are not pre-committing to a particular rate path.
In any case, we stand ready to adjust all of our instruments within our mandate to ensure that inflation stabilises sustainably at our medium-term target and to preserve the smooth functioning of monetary policy transmission.
We are now ready to take your questions.
 
Compliments of the European Central BankThe post ECB | Monetary Policy Statement: Christine Lagarde, President of the ECB, Luis de Guindos, Vice-President of the ECB first appeared on European American Chamber of Commerce New York [EACCNY] | Your Partner for Transatlantic Business Resources.

EACC

EU Delegation to the US | EU in the US Top 10

A Balanced Partnership
HR/VP Kallas discussed EU-U.S. cooperation on global issues with U.S. Secretary of State Marco Rubio. The EU-U.S. trade balance is well balanced, both sides have complementary strengths.
800 Million Citizens
Our partnership is the world’s most extensive bilateral trade and investment relationship and our economies are integrated. Read the EU Ambassador Neliupšienė’s remarks to the press.
World Economic Forum
“European companies in the U.S. employ 3.5 million Americans. And another million American jobs depend directly on trade with Europe. Entire supply chains stretch on both sides of the Atlantic.” Learn more about the EU Competitiveness Compass.
— European Commission President Ursula von der Leyen
EU in Pennsylvania
Ambassador Neliupšienė visited Philadelphia to meet the Mayor and highlight the EU’s $72 billion investment in the state and the creation of over 250,000 jobs. We also hosted a group of students from the University of Pennsylvania!
American Farm Bureau Convention
In San Antonio, Texas, EU officials engaged with farmers and industry leaders to highlight innovation in agriculture and the importance of EU-U.S. cooperation.
Holocaust Remembrance Day
“We remember all the victims murdered during the Holocaust and mark the 80 years since the liberation of the Nazi concentration and extermination camp Auschwitz-Birkenau. This memory must be passed to future generations.”
—European Commission
We Stand with Ukraine
European Council President António Costa met President Zelenskyy and assured him of the EU’s support, including through sanctions against Russia.
Pints & Policy with the EU
Defense Attaché Henning Faltin and GMF Managing Director Kristine Berzina discussed the EU-U.S. security partnership and the EU’s vision for boosting its defense capabilities. Learn more.
Towards a Common Future
The future of the Western Balkans is with the European Union, so it is important that we remain in close contact with the Ambassadors. Thank you to Atlantic Council experts for their insights!
 
Compliments of the European External Action ServiceThe post EU Delegation to the US | EU in the US Top 10 first appeared on European American Chamber of Commerce New York [EACCNY] | Your Partner for Transatlantic Business Resources.

EACC

ECB | Survey on the Access to Finance of Enterprises: firms report lower interest rates but a small decline in bank loan availability

Firms reported declining bank interest rates on loans, although indicating a slight further tightening of other lending conditions.
There was a slight increase in the bank financing gap compared with the previous quarter as firms reported a small reduction in bank loan availability and no change in the need for bank loans.
Firms’ inflation expectations increased slightly, with their median expectations for annual inflation in one, three and five years all standing at 3.0%, 0.1 percentage points higher across all three horizons.
Nearly half of the firms surveyed see the ECB’s inflation target at 2% and these firms have lower inflation expectations than those believing the target to be significantly higher.

In the most recent round of the Survey on the Access to Finance of Enterprises (SAFE), euro area firms reported a decrease in interest rates on bank loans (a net -4%, compared with a net 4% reporting an increase in the previous quarter), although a net 22% (30% in the previous quarter) observed increases in other financing costs (i.e. charges, fees and commissions) (Chart 1).
In this survey round, firms reported a small decline in the availability of bank loans in the fourth quarter of 2024 (a net -2%, down from a net 1% reporting an increase in the previous quarter) (Chart 2). At the same time, firms indicated no change in the need for bank loans, compared with 2% reporting a decrease in the third quarter of 2024. This led the financing gap – an index capturing the difference between the need for and availability of bank loans – to increase for a net 1% of firms, compared with a net 2% of firms reporting a decrease in the previous survey round. Looking ahead, firms expect small improvements in the availability of external financing over the next three months.
More firms perceived the general economic outlook to be the main factor hampering the availability of external financing than in the previous survey round (a net percentage of -22%, compared with -20%). A net 8% of firms indicated that their perception of banks’ willingness to lend, which may reflect banks’ risk aversion, had improved further (up from 6%).
A net 6% of enterprises reported an increase in turnover over the last three months, down from 7% in the previous survey round, with a net 11% of firms remaining optimistic about developments in the next quarter. An increased percentage of firms saw a deterioration in their profits compared with the previous survey round (a net percentage of -14%). The survey indicates that the net percentage of firms reporting an increase in cost pressures continued to decline.
Firms continued to expect the increase in their selling prices and wages to moderate over the next 12 months (Chart 3). Selling prices were expected to increase by 2.9% on average (down from 3.0% in the previous survey round), while the corresponding figure for wages was 3.3% (down from 3.5% in the previous round).
Firms’ inflation expectations increased slightly, bringing a halt to the previous declines (Chart 4). Median expectations for annual inflation in one, three and five years all stood at 3.0%, thus increasing by 0.1 percentage points for all three horizons. For inflation in five years, fewer firms reported balanced risks (33%). The increase in the percentage of firms seeing upside risks (51%, up from 46%) was similar to the rise in the share of those perceiving risks to the downside (16%, up from 12%).
To better understand firms’ awareness of and attention to inflation developments, a new set of ad hoc questions was introduced in this survey round. Firms were asked about the factors they believe influenced inflation in 2024, their level of attention to actual inflation, and how this attention has shifted compared with a year ago. Firms cited non-labour input costs rather than wage costs or profits as the primary factor influencing inflation in 2024. Additionally, firms were asked about the inflation target set by the European Central Bank (ECB). Nearly half of the firms surveyed see that target at 2%, and these firms have lower inflation expectations than those believing the target to be significantly higher than 2%.
The report published today presents the main results of the 33rdround of the SAFE survey for the euro area. The survey was conducted between 20 November and 18 December 2024. Firms were asked about conditions over the three-month period from October to December 2024. The sample comprised 5,393 enterprises in the euro area, of which 4,997 (93%) had fewer than 250 employees.
For media queries, please contact Nicos Keranis nicos.keranis@ecb.europa.eu, tel.: +49 172 758 7237.
Notes

The report on this SAFE survey round, together with the questionnaire and methodological information, is available on the ECB’s website.
Detailed data series for the individual euro area countries and aggregate euro area results are available on the ECB Data Portal.

Chart 1
Changes in the terms and conditions of bank financing for euro area enterprises

(net percentages of respondents)

Base: Enterprises that had applied for bank loans (including subsidised bank loans), credit lines, or bank or credit card overdrafts. The figures refer to pilot 2 and rounds 30 to 33 of the survey (October-December 2023 to October-December 2024).
Notes: Net percentages are the difference between the percentage of enterprises reporting an increase for a given factor and the percentage reporting a decrease. The data included in the chart refer to Question 10 of the survey.

Chart 2
Changes in euro area enterprises’ financing needs and the availability of bank loans

(net percentages of respondents)

Base: Enterprises for which the instrument in question is relevant (i.e. they have used it or considered using it). Respondents replying “not applicable” or “don’t know” are excluded. The figures refer to pilot 2 and rounds 30 to 33 of the survey (October-December 2023 to October-December 2024).
Notes: The financing gap indicator combines both financing needs and the availability of bank loans at firm level. The indicator of the perceived change in the financing gap takes a value of 1 (-1) if the need increases (decreases) and availability decreases (increases). If enterprises perceive only a one-sided increase (decrease) in the financing gap, the variable is assigned a value of 0.5 (-0.5). A positive value for the indicator points to a widening of the financing gap. Values are multiplied by 100 to obtain weighted net balances in percentages. The data included in the chart refer to Questions 5 and 9 of the survey.

Chart 3
Expectations for selling prices, wages, input costs and employees one year ahead, by size class

Base: All enterprises. The figures refer to rounds 29 to 33 (April-September 2023 to October-December 2024) of the survey, with firms’ replies collected in the last month of the respective survey waves.
Notes: Weighted average euro area firm expectations of changes in selling prices, wages of current employees, non-labour input costs and number of employees for the next 12 months using survey weights. The statistics are computed after trimming the data at the country-specific 1st and 99th percentiles. The data included in the chart refer to Question 34 of the survey.

Chart 4
Firms’ median expectations for euro area inflation by size class

(annual percentages)

Base: All enterprises. The figures refer to pilot 2 and rounds 30 to 33 (October-December 2023 to October-December 2024) of the survey, with firms’ replies collected in the last month of the respective survey waves.
Notes: Survey-weighted median of euro area firms’ expectations for euro area inflation in one year, three years and five years. The statistics are computed after trimming the data at the country-specific 1st and 99th percentiles. The data included in the chart refer to Question 31 of the survey.

 
Compliments of the European Central BankThe post ECB | Survey on the Access to Finance of Enterprises: firms report lower interest rates but a small decline in bank loan availability first appeared on European American Chamber of Commerce New York [EACCNY] | Your Partner for Transatlantic Business Resources.